Cryptocurrency: Money, Funny-Money, and Crypto - A Gold Perspective...

grarpamp grarpamp at gmail.com
Sat Nov 13 09:27:52 PST 2021


Money, Funny-Money, and Crypto

https://www.goldmoney.com/research/goldmoney-insights/money-funny-money-and-crypto

That the post-industrial era of fiat currencies is coming to an end is
becoming a real possibility. Major economies are now stalling while
price inflation is just beginning to take off, following the excessive
currency debasement in all major jurisdictions since the Lehman crisis
and accelerated even further by covid.

The dilemma now faced by central banks is whether to raise interest
rates sufficiently to tackle price inflation and lend support to their
currencies, or to take one last gamble on yet more stimulus in the
hope that recessions can be avoided.

Politics and neo-Keynesian economics strongly favour monetary
inflation and continued interest rate suppression. But following that
course leads to the destruction of currencies. So, how should ordinary
people protect themselves from currency risk?

To assist them, this article draws out the distinctions between money,
currency, and bank credit. It examines the claims of cryptocurrencies
to be replacement money or currencies, explaining why they will be
denied either role. An update is given on the uncanny resemblance
between current neo-Keynesian monetary inflation and support for
financial asset prices, compared with John Law’s proto-Keynesian
policies which destroyed the French economy and currency in 1720.

Assuming we continue to follow Law’s playbook, an understanding why
money is only physical gold and silver and nothing else will be vital
to surviving what appears to be a looming crisis in financial assets
and currencies.

Introduction

With the recent acceleration in the growth of money supply it is
readily apparent that government spending is increasingly financed
through monetary inflation. Those who hoped it would be a temporary
phenomenon are being shown to have been overly optimistic. The excuse
that its expansion was only a one-off event limited to supporting
businesses and consumers through the covid pandemic is now being
extended to seeing them through continuing logistics disruptions along
with other unexpected problems. We now face an economic slowdown which
will reduce government revenues and, according to policy planners, may
require additional monetary stimulation to preclude.

Along with never-ending budget deficits, for the foreseeable future
monetary inflation at elevated levels is here to stay. The threat to
the future purchasing power of currencies should be obvious, yet few
people appear to be attributing rising prices to prior monetary
expansion. David Ricardo’s equation of exchange whereby changes in the
quantity of money are shown to affect its purchasing power down the
line has disappeared from the inflation narrative and is all but
forgotten.

That the users of the medium of exchange ultimately determine its
utility is ignored. It is now assumed to be the state’s function to
decide what acts as money and not its users. Instead, we are told that
the state’s fiat currency is money, will always be money and that
prices are rising due to failures of the capitalist system. Central to
the deception is to call currency money, and to persist in describing
its management by the state as monetary policy. And money supply is
always the supply of fiat currency in all its forms.

That these so-called monetary policies have failed and continue to do
so is becoming more widely appreciated. It is the anti-capitalistic
attitude of state planners which absolves them from the blame of
mismanaging the relationship between their currencies and economies by
blaming private sector actors when their policies fail. Instead of
acting as the people’s servants, governments have become their
controllers, expecting the public’s sheep-like cooperation in economic
and monetary affairs. The state issues its currency backed by
unquestioned faith and credit in the government’s monopoly to issue
and manage it. Seeming to recognise the potential failure of their
currency monopolies many central banks now intend to issue a new
version, a central bank digital currency to give greater control over
how citizens use and value it.

Without doubt, the dangers from fiat currency instability are
increasing. Never has it been more important for ordinary people, its
users, to understand what real money constitutes and its difference
from state-issued currencies. Not only are new currencies in the form
of central bank digital currencies being proposed but some suggest
that distributed ledger cryptocurrencies, which are beyond the control
of governments, will be adopted when state fiat currencies fail, an
eventual development for which increasing numbers of people expect.

The currency scene is descending into a confusion for which policy
planners are unprepared. Fiat currencies are failing, evidenced by
declining purchasing power. Not only is it the lesson of history; not
only are governments resorting to the printing press or its digital
equivalent, but it is naïve to think that governments desire monetary
stability over satisfying the interests of one group over those of
another. By suppressing interest rates, central banks favour borrowers
over depositors. By issuing additional currency they transfer wealth
from their governments’ electors. The transfer is never equitable
either, with early receivers of new currency getting to spend it
before prices have adjusted to accommodate the increased quantity in
circulation. Those who receive it last find that prices have risen
because of currency dilution while their income has been devalued. The
beneficiaries are those close to government and the banks who expand
credit by ledger entry. The losers are the poor and pensioners — the
people who in democratic theory are more morally entitled to
protection from currency debasement than anyone else.
The true role of money

In the late eighteenth century, a French businessman and economist,
Jean-Baptiste Say, noticed that when France’s currencies failed during
the Revolution, people simply exchanged goods for other goods. A
cobbler would exchange the shoes and boots he made for the food and
other items he required to feed and sustain his family. The principles
behind the division of labour had continued without money. But it
became clear to Say that the role of money was to facilitate this
exchange more efficiently than could be achieved in its absence. For
Keynesian economists, this is the inconvenient truth of Say’s law.

The division of labour, which permits individuals to deploy their
personal skills to the greatest benefit for themselves and therefore
for others, remains central to the commercial actions of all humanity.
It is the mainspring of progress. A medium of exchange commonly
accepted by society not only facilitates the efficient exchange of
goods produced through individual skills but it allows a producer to
retain money temporarily for future consumption. This can be because
he has a surplus for his immediate requirements, or he decides to
invest it in improving his product, increasing his output, or for
other purposes than immediate consumption.

Whether it is a corporation, manager, employee, or sole trader;
whether the product be a good or a service— all qualify as producers.
Everyone earning a living or striving to make a profit is a producer.

Over the many millennia that have elapsed since the end of barter,
people dividing their labour settled on metallic money as the mediums
of exchange; recognisable, divisible, commonly accepted, and being
scarce also valuable. And as civilisation progressed gold, silver, and
copper were coined into recognisable units. These media of exchange in
their unadulterated form were money, and even though they were stamped
with images of kings and emperors, they were no one’s liability.

Nowadays, humans across the planet still recognise physical gold and
silver as true money. But it is a mistake to think they guarantee
price stability — only that they are more stable than other media of
exchange, which is why they have always survived and re-emerged after
alternatives have failed. This is the key to understanding why they
guaranteed money substitutes, notably through industrial revolutions,
and remain money to this day.

Britain led the way in replacing silver as its long-standing monetary
standard with gold, relegating silver to a secondary coinage. In 1817
the new gold sovereign was introduced at the exchange rate equivalent
of 113 grains (0.2354 ounces troy) to the pound currency. A working
gold standard, whereby bank notes were exchangeable for gold coin
commenced in 1821, remaining at that fixed rate until the outbreak of
the First World War in 1914.

By 1900, the gold standard had international as well as domestic
aspects. It implied that nations settled balance of payment
differences with each other in gold, although in practice this seems
to have happened relatively little.

Many smaller nations, while having domestic gold circulation, did not
bother to keep physical gold in reserve, but held sterling balances
which, again, were regarded as being as good as gold. The Bank of
England had a remarkably small reserve of under 200 tonnes in 1900,
compared with the Bank of France which held 544 tonnes, the Imperial
Bank of Russia with 661 tonnes, and the US Treasury with 602 tonnes.
But even though remarkably little gold was held by the Bank of
England, over 1,400 tonnes of sovereign coins had been minted in
Australia and the UK and were in public circulation. Therefore, some
£200m of the UK and its empire’s money supply was in physical gold
(the equivalent of £62bn at today’s prices).
The relationship between gold and prices

Metallic money’s purchasing power fluctuates, influenced by long-term
factors such as changes in mine output and population growth. Gold is
also held for non-monetary purposes such as jewellery though the
distinction between bullion held as money and jewellery can be fuzzy.
A minor use is industrial. The degree of coin circulation relative to
the quantity of substitutes also affects its purchasing power, as
experience from nineteenth century Britain attests.

The economic progress of the industrial revolution increased the
volume of goods relative to the quantity of money and
money-substitutes (bank notes and bank deposits subject to cheques),
so the general level of producer prices declined, even though they
varied with changes in the level of bank credit. That generally held
until the late-1880s, when bank credit in the economy expanded on the
back of increased shipments of gold from South Africa. Furthermore, a
combination of rising demand for industrial commodities through
economic expansion of the entire British empire and more currencies
linking themselves to gold indirectly via managed exchange rates
against pounds and other gold-backed currencies all contributed to
reverse the declining trend of wholesale prices between 1894—1914.

Consequently, wholesale prices no longer declined but tended to
increase modestly. This is shown in Figure 1.

Figure 1 also explodes the myth in central bank monetary policy
circles that varying interest rates controls money’s purchasing power
by “pricing” money.

Demand for credit is set by the economic calculations of businessmen
and entrepreneurs, not idle rentiers as assumed by Keynes who named
this paradox after Arthur Gibson, who pointed it out in 1923. The
explanation eluded Keynes and his followers but is simple. In
assessing the profitability of production, the most important variable
(assuming that the means of production are readily available) is
anticipated prices for finished products. Changes in borrowing rates,
reflecting the affordability of interest that could be paid therefore
do not precede changes in prices but follow changes in prices for this
reason.

While fluctuations in the sum of the quantities of money, currency and
credit affect the general level of prices, there is an additional
effect of the value placed on these components by its users. History
has demonstrated that the most stable value is placed on gold coin,
which is what qualifies it as money. It has been said that priced in
gold a Roman toga 2,000 years ago cost the same as a lounge suit
today. But we don’t need to go back that far for our evidence. Figure
2 shows WTI oil priced in dollars, the world’s reserve currency, and
gold both indexed to 1986. Clearly, the dollar is significantly less
reliable than gold as a stable medium of exchange.

So long as gold is freely exchangeable for currency, this stability is
imparted to currency as well. When it is suspected that this
exchangeability is likely to be compromised, coin becomes hoarded and
disappears from circulation. The purchasing power of the currency then
becomes dependent on a combination of changes in its quantity and
changes in faith in the issuer. Bank deposits face the additional risk
of faith in the bank’s ability to pay its debts.

In summary, the general level of prices tends to fall gradually over
time in an economy where gold coin circulates as the underlying medium
of exchange, and when faith in the currency as its circulating
alternative is unquestioned. The existence of a coin exchange facility
lifts the purchasing power of the currency above where it would
otherwise be without a functioning standard. Even when gold exchange
for a fiat currency becomes restricted, the purchasing power of the
currency continues to enjoy some support, as we saw during the Bretton
Woods Agreement.
The distinction between money and currency

So far, we have defined money, which is metallic and physical. Now we
turn to what is erroneously taken to be money, which is currency.
Originally, the dollar and pound sterling were freely exchangeable by
its users for silver and then gold coin, so state-issued currencies
came to be assumed to be as good as money. But its exchangeability
diminished over time. In the United Kingdom exchangeability of
sterling currency for gold coin ceased with the outbreak of
hostilities in 1914, though sovereigns still exist as money officially
today. They are simply subject to Gresham’s law, driven out of general
circulation by inferior currency. The post-war gold standard of
1925-32 was a bullion standard whereby only 400-ounce bars could be
demanded for circulating currency, which failed to tie in sterling to
money proper.

In the United States, gold coin was exchangeable for dollars in the
decades before April 1933 at $20.67 to the ounce. Bank failures
following the Wall Street crash encouraged citizens to exchange dollar
deposits for gold, and foreign holders of dollar deposits similarly
demanded gold, leading to a drain on American gold reserves. By
Executive Order 6102 in April 1933 President Roosevelt banned private
sector ownership of gold coin, gold bullion and gold certificates,
thereby ending the gold coin standard and forcing Americans to accept
inconvertible dollar currency as the circulating medium of exchange.
This was followed by a devaluation of the dollar on the international
exchanges to $35 to the ounce in January 1934.

The entire removal of money from the global currency system was a
gradual process, driven by a progression of currency events, until
August 1971 when President Nixon ended the Bretton Woods Agreement.
>From then on, the US dollar became the world’s reserve currency,
commonly used for pricing commodities and energy on international
markets. But following the Nixon shock, the dollar had become purely
fiat.

Unlike gold coin, which has no counterparty risk, fiat currency is
evidence of either a liability of an issuing central bank or of a
commercial bank. It is not money. The fact that money, being gold or
silver coin does not commonly circulate as media of exchange, cannot
alter this fact. Since the dawn of modern banking with London’s
goldsmiths in the seventeenth century, who deployed ledger debits and
credits, most currency entitlements have been held in bank deposits,
which are not the property of deposit customers, being liabilities of
the banks and owed to them. It started with depositors placing specie
with goldsmiths or transferring currency to them from other accounts
on the understanding a goldsmith would deploy the funds so acquired to
obtain sufficient profit to pay a 6% interest on deposits. To earn
this return, it was agreed by the depositor that the funds would
become the goldsmith’s property to be used as the goldsmith saw fit.

Goldsmiths and their banking successors were and still are dealers in
credit. As the goldsmiths’ banking business evolved, they would create
deposits by extending credit to borrowers. A loan to the borrower
appeared as an asset on a goldsmith’s balance sheet, which through
double-entry book-keeping was balanced by a liability being the
deposit facility from which the borrower would draw down the loan.
Thus, money and currency issued by banks as claims upon them were
replaced entirely by book-entry liabilities owed to depositors,
encashable into specie, central bank currency or banker’s cheque only
on demand.

Through the expansion of bank credit, which is matched by the creation
of deposits through double-entry book-keeping, commercial banks create
liabilities subject to withdrawal as currency to this day. That there
is an underlying cycle of expansion and contraction of bank credit is
evidenced by the composite price index and bond yields between 1817
and 1885 shown in Figure 1 above. But so long as money, that is gold
coin, remained exchangeable with currency and bank deposits on demand,
fluctuations in outstanding bank credit only had a relatively
short-term effect on the general level of prices. And as explained
above, the expansion of the quantity of above-ground gold stocks from
South African mines in the late 1880s contributed to the general level
of prices increasing in the final decade of the nineteenth century
until the First World War.

Following the Great War, the earlier creation of the Federal Reserve
Board in the United States led to the expansion of circulating dollar
currency, fuelling the Roaring Twenties and the Wall Street bubble,
followed by the Wall Street crash and the depression. These calamities
were the inevitable consequence of excessive credit creation in the
1920s. The error made by statist economists at the time (and ever
since) was to ignore what caused the depression, believing it to be a
contemporaneous failure of capitalism instead of the consequence of
earlier currency debasement and interest rate suppression. From then
on, this error has been perpetuated by statists frustrated by the
discipline imposed upon them by monetary gold. The solution was seen
to be to remove money from the currency system so that the state would
have unlimited flexibility to manage economic outcomes.

With America dominating the global economy after the First World War,
her use of the dollar both domestically and internationally had begun
to dominate global economic outcomes. The errors of earlier currency
expansion ahead of and during the Roaring Twenties, admittedly
exacerbated by the introduction of farm machinery, led to a global
slump in agricultural prices the following decade. And the additional
error of Glass Stegall tariffs collapsed global trade in all goods.

Following the Second World War, secondary wars in Korea and Vietnam
led to exported dollars being accumulated and then sold by foreign
central banks for American’s gold reserves. In 1948, America had
21,628.4 tonnes of gold reserves, 72% of the world total. By 1971,
when the facility for central banks to encash dollars for gold was
suspended, US gold reserves had fallen to 12,398 tonnes, 34% of world
gold reserves. Today it stands officially at 8,133.5 tonnes, being
less than 23% of world gold reserves — figures independently unaudited
and suspected by many observers to overstate the true position.

The consequences of currency expansion for the relationship between
money and currency since the two were completely severed in 1971 is
shown in Figure 3.

Since 1960 (the indexed base of the chart) above-ground gold stocks
have increased from 62,475 tonnes by about 200% to 189,000 tonnes —
offset to a large degree by world population growth.[iv] M3 broad
money has increased by 70 times, the disparity in these rates of
increase being adjusted by the increase in the dollar price of money,
with the dollar losing 98% of its purchasing power relative to gold.
By basing the chart on 1960 much of the currency expansion which led
to the collapse of the London gold pool in the mid-1960s is captured,
illustrating the strains in the relationship that led to the Nixon
shock.
The rival status of cryptocurrencies

Over the last decade, led by bitcoin cryptocurrencies have become a
popular hedge against fiat currency debasement. Bitcoin has a finite
limit of 21 million coins, having less than 2¼ million yet to be
mined. And of those issued, some are irretrievably lost, theoretically
adding to their value.

Fans of cryptocurrencies are unusual, because they have grasped the
essential weakness of state-issued fiat currencies ahead of the wider
public. Armed with this knowledge they claim that distributed ledger
technology independent from governments will form the basis of
tomorrow’s money. It has led to a speculative frenzy, driving
bitcoin’s price from a reported 10,000 for two pizzas in 2010
(therefore worth less than a cent each) to over $60,000 today. If, as
hodlers hope, bitcoin replaces all state-issued fiat currencies when
they fail, then the increase in its dollar value has much further to
go.

In theory there are reasons that bitcoin and similar cryptocurrencies
can become media of exchange in a limited capacity, but never money,
the basis that all currencies referred to for their original validity.
Indeed, some transactions following the original pizza purchase have
occurred since, but they are very few.

The reasons bitcoin or rival cryptocurrencies are unlikely to be
accepted widely as currencies, let alone as a replacement for money,
are best summed up in the following bullet points.

    To replace money, as opposed to currencies, bitcoin would have to
be accepted as a replacement for both gold and silver. Beyond the
imagination of tech-savvy enthusiasts, making up perhaps less than one
in two hundred transacting humans, it is impossible to see bitcoin
achieving this goal, because they represent a vanishingly small number
of the global population. There can be little doubt that if fiat
currencies lose their utility the overwhelming majority of transacting
individuals will desire physical money, and not another form of
digital media, which currencies in the main and cryptocurrencies have
become.

    Despite the advance of technology not everyone yet possesses the
knowledge, media, or the reliable electricity and internet connections
to conduct transactions in cryptocurrencies. Remote theft of them is
easier and more profitable than that of gold and silver coin.
Cryptocurrencies are too dependent on undefinable risk factors for
transactional ubiquity.

    The number of rival cryptocurrencies has proliferated. It is
estimated that there are now over 6,800 in existence compared with 180
government-issued currencies. They represent both an inflation of
numbers and values, which if unsatisfied already makes the seventeenth
century tulip mania look like to have been a relatively minor speed
bump in comparison. In only a decade they have grown to $750 billion
in value based on an unproven concept stimulating unallayed human
greed at the expense of considered reason.

    By way of contrast, gold’s strength as money is its flexibility of
supply from other uses combined with its record of ensuring price
stability. As we saw in Figure 1’s illustration of the relationship
between prices and borrowing costs, assuming the factors of production
are available the stability of prices under a gold standard permits an
assessment of final product values at the commencement of an
investment in production. There is no such certainty with bitcoin or
rival cryptocurrencies because a strictly finite quantity would make
it impossible to calculate final prices at the end of an investment in
production. Without providing the means for economic calculation, any
money or currency replacement will fail.

    Unless they disappear with their currencies, central banks will
never sanction distributed ledger currencies beyond their control
acting as a general medium of exchange. This is one reason why they
are working to introduce their own central bank digital currencies,
allowing them to maintain statist control over currencies while
extending powers over how they are used. Furthermore, central banks do
not own cryptocurrencies, but they do officially own 35,554 tonnes of
gold, having never discarded true money completely.[vi] Events have
proved that they are even reluctant to allow monetary gold to
circulate, not least because it would call into question the
credibility of their fiat currencies. But if there is a fall-back
position in the demise of fiat, it will be based on central bank gold
and never on a private-sector cryptocurrency.

We should also consider what happens to cryptocurrencies in the event
of a fiat currency collapse. The point behind any money or currency is
that it must possess all the objective value in a transaction with all
subjectivity to be found in the goods or services being exchanged. It
requires the currency to be scarce, but not so much that its value
measured in goods is expected to continually rise. If that was the
case, then its ability to circulate would become impaired through
hoarding.

We are left with questioning whether bitcoin can ever possess a purely
objective value in transactions. Their potential role as a transacting
currency will also evaporate along with fiat because these will be the
circumstances where all currencies which cannot be issued as credible
gold substitutes will become valueless, because if any currency is to
survive the end of the fiat regime it will require action by central
banks combined with new laws and regulations which can only come from
governments. The nightmare for crypto enthusiasts is that central
banks will be forced eventually to mobilise their gold reserves to
back credibly what is left of their currencies’ collapsing purchasing
power.

We are providing an answer to another question over the fate of
cryptocurrencies in the event that central banks are forced to
mobilise their gold reserves, turning fiat currencies into credible
money substitutes. Admittedly, it is unlikely to be a simple decision
with the problem beyond the understanding of statist policy advisers
and with competing interests seeking to influence the outcome. But,
there can be only one action that will allow the state and banking
system to retain control over currencies and credit, which is to back
them with gold reserves, preferably with a gold coin standard.

When that moment is anticipated, cryptocurrencies as potential
circulating currencies will become fully redundant. They are then
likely to lose most of or all their value as replacement currencies.
Furthermore, it is hard to find anyone who currently holds a
cryptocurrency who does not hope to cash in by selling them at higher
prices for their national currencies. They have been bought for
speculation and investment with little or no intention of ultimately
spending them. Therefore, we can assume that the demise of fiat
currencies, far from inviting replacements by bitcoin and its
imitators, will also mean the death of the cryptocurrency phenomenon
in a general return towards a money standard, which always has been
physical and metallic.
The progression towards currency destruction

In last week’s article for Goldmoney I suggested four waypoints to
mark the route towards the ending of the fiat currency system. The
similarity of current events with those of John Law’s inflation and
subsequent collapse of the Mississippi bubble and of the French livre
so far is striking, but this time it’s on a global scale. The John Law
experience offers us a template for what is already happening to
financial assets and currencies today — hence the four waypoints.

Briefly described, John Law was a proto-Keynesian money crank who
operated a policy of inflating the values of his principal assets, the
Banque Royale and his Mississippi venture, by issuing shares in partly
paid form with calls due later. Ten per cent down translated into
fortunes for early subscribers as share prices rose from L140 in June
1717 to over L10,000 in January 1720, fuelled by a bitcoin-style
buying frenzy. But when calls became due in January 1720 and a scheme
to merge the Banque Royale with the Mississippi venture was proposed,
shares began to be sold to pay the calls and take up rights to new
issues. Law used his position as controller of the currency to issue
fiat livres to buy shares in the market to support prices, measures
that finally failed in May. Priced in livres, the shares fell to under
3,500 by November. In sterling, they fell from £330 in January to
below £50 in September. After October, there was no exchange rate for
livres against sterling implying the livre had lost all its exchange
value.

By injecting cash into investing institutions in return for government
bonds, central banks are following a remarkably similar policy today.
Quantitative easing by the US’s central bank, which since March 2020
has injected over $2 trillion into US pension funds and insurance
companies to invest in higher risk assets than government and agency
bonds, is no less than a repetition of John Law’s policy of inflating
asset values to ensure a spreading wealth effect, while ensuring
finance is facilitated for the state.

Last night (3 November) the Fed was forced to announce a phased
reduction of quantitative easing to allay fears of intractable price
inflation. The question now arises as to how many months of QE
reduction it will take to deflate the financial asset bubble. And what
will then be the Fed’s response: will QE be increased again in a
repetition of the John Law proto-Keynesian mistakes?

There comes a point where the prices of goods reflect the increased
quantity of currency in circulation. Increases in the general level of
prices inevitably lead to rising levels for interest rates, and the
creation of credit in the main banking centres begin to go into
reverse. John Law found that share prices could then no longer be
supported, and the Mississippi bubble burst in May 1720; a fate which
equity markets today will almost certainly face, because price rises
for goods and services are now proving intractable.

The outcome of Law’s proto-Keynesianism was a collapse in Mississippi
shares, and the complete destruction of the livre. The similarity with
the situation in financial markets today is truly remarkable. There
are now no good options for policy makers. Hampered by similar
neo-Keynesian errors and beliefs, central bankers and politicians lack
the resolve to stop events leading inexorably towards the destruction
of their currencies. The first waypoint in last week’s article for
Goldmoney is now being seen: a growing realisation that major
economies, particularly the US and UK, face the prospect of a
combination of rising prices accompanied by an economic slump,
frequently diagnosed as stagflation.

Stagflation is a misnomer. Monetary inflation is a con which in
smaller doses provides the illusion of stimulus. But there comes a
point where the transfer of wealth from the productive economy to the
government is too great to bear and the economy begins to collapse.
While it is impossible to judge where that point lies, the
accumulation of monetary inflation in recent years now weighs heavily
on all major economies.

The conditions today closely replicate those in France in late-1719
and early 1720. Prices were rising in the rural areas as well as in
the cities, impoverishing the peasantry and asset inflation was
running into headwinds, about to impoverish the beneficiaries of the
bubble’s wealth effect as well.
Conclusion

If central banks decide to protect their currencies, they must let
markets determine interest rates. With prices rising officially at
over 5% in the US (more like 15% on independent estimates) the rise in
interest rates will not only crash all financial asset values from
fixed interest to equities, but force governments to rein in their
spending to eliminate deficits. This will involve greater cuts than
currently indicated, because of loss of tax revenues. Indeed,
mandatory spending will put socialising governments in an impossible
position.

But even these measures are unlikely to protect currencies, because of
extensive foreign ownership of the US dollar. Foreigners hold total
some $33 trillion in financial assets and bank deposits, much of which
will be liquidated or lost in a bear market. Long experience suggests
that funds rescued from overexposure to foreign currencies will be
repatriated.

Alternatively, attempts to continue the inflationary policies of
Keynesian money cranks will undermine currencies more rapidly, but
this is almost certainly the line of least policy resistance — until
it is too late.

It has never been more important for the hapless citizen to recognise
what is happening to currencies and to understand the fallacies behind
cryptocurrencies. They are not practical replacements for state-issued
currencies and are likely to turn out to be just another aspect of the
financial bubble. The only protection from an increasingly likely
collapse of the fiat money system and all that sails with it is to
understand what constitutes money as opposed to currency; and that is
only physical gold and silver coins and bars.


More information about the cypherpunks mailing list