What Brought on the French Revolution?

Mises Daily Article article at mises.org
Fri Apr 9 06:15:18 PDT 2004


<http://www.mises.org/fullstory.asp?control=1489>http://www.mises.org/fullstory.asp?control=1489

What Brought on the French Revolution?

By H.A. Scott Trask

[Posted April 9, 2004]

 No matter how much the American economy grows during the next decade, the
government will have serious trouble funding expanding entitlements,
increased education spending, and ongoing wars in the Middle East, while
maintaining a global military constabulary and presence everywhere.
Something has to give. No matter how one crunches the numbers, a crisis is
looming, and Americans are bound to see their standard of living fall and
their global empire collapse.

It has happened before. Consider that seminal and catastrophic event that
inaugurated the era of mass politics, bureaucratic centralism, and the
ideological statethe French Revolution. It is a large and complex event
worthy of a Gibbon, but it may not have happened at all if the French
monarchy had balanced its budget.

While the causes of the Revolution are many, the cause of the crisis that
brought on the Revolution is not. It was a fiscal and credit crisis that
weakened the authority and confidence of the monarchy so much that it
thought it had to convene a defunct political assembly before it had safely
carried out a successful program of liberal constitutional and free market
reform. It would be as if the American federal government called a
constitutional convention with an open agenda and hoped that all would go
smoothly. The Estates General lasted only a little over a month before the
leaders of the Third Estate (the bourgeoisie, artisans, and peasantry)
transformed it into a National Assembly and took political power from the
monarchy. The Revolution was on.

Revisionist historians have challenged the standard interpretation of
pre-revolutionary France as a country with a stagnant economy, an oppressed
peasantry, a shackled bourgeoisie, and an archaic political structure. In
Citizens (1989), Simon Schama describes France under Louis XVI as a rapidly
modernizing nation with entrepreneurial nobles, a reform-minded monarchy,
nascent industrialization, growing commerce, scientific progress, and
energetic intendants (royal administrators in the provinces).

Moreover, Montesquieu was in vogue; the English mixed constitution was the
cynosure of political reform, and the economic philosophy of physiocracy,
with its belief in economic law and advocacy of laissez faire, had
discredited the dogmas of state mercantilism.

Turgot argued perceptively that another war with England would derail his
reform program, bankrupt the state, and, even if successful, do little to
weaken British power.

In 1774, Louis XVI appointed Jacques Turgot, a Physiocrat, to be
Controller-General of Finances. Turgot believed that subsidies,
regulations, and tariffs were crippling productivity and enterprise in
France. End them, he advised the king, and business would thrive and state
revenues increase. He proposed an ambitious reform program that included
taking down internal custom barriers, lifting price controls on grain,
abolishing the guilds and the corvee (forced labor service), and devolving
political power to newly created provincial assemblies (two of which he
established). Turgot envisioned a federated France, with a chain of elected
bodies extending from the village through the provinces to some form of
national assembly.

Not surprisingly, there was both aristocratic and popular opposition to
these reforms, but what really doomed them was Turgot's inveterate
opposition to French intervention in the American War of Independence. Many
were still stewing over the humiliating and catastrophic defeat suffered by
France in the Seven Years' War (17561763). The country had lost her North
American possessions (Quebec, Louisiana) and all of French India, except
two trading stations. The foreign minister (Vergennes) calculated that by
helping the Americans gain their independence they could weaken the British
Empire, gain revenge, and restore France's previous position as one of the
world's two superpowers.

 Turgot argued perceptively that another war with England would derail his
reform program, bankrupt the state, and, even if successful, do little to
weaken British power. "The first gunshot will drive the state to
bankruptcy," he warned the king. It was to no avail. International power
politics and considerations of national prestige took precedence over
domestic reform, and the king dismissed him in May 1776. He would be proved
right on all three points.

The French began covertly supplying war material to the rebellious
colonists in 1777, and in 1778 they signed a treaty of alliance with the
Americans. Throughout the war, they supplied hard money loans, and
underwrote others for the purchase of war supplies in Europe. In 1780, they
landed a 5,000-man army in Rhode Island. In 1781, the French navy blockaded
Lord Cornwallis's army at Yorktown.

Turgot's successor Jacques Necker, a Swiss banker, financed these
expenditures almost entirely through loans. Although successful, France's
intervention cost 1.3 billion livres and almost doubled her national debt.
Schama writes, "No state with imperial pretensions has, in fact, ever
subordinated what it takes to be irreducible military interests to the
considerations of a balanced budget. And like apologists for military force
in twentieth-century America," imperialists "in eighteenth century France
pointed to the country's vast demographic and economic reserves and a
flourishing economy to sustain the burden."  Even more, they claimed that
prosperity was "contingent on such military expenditures, both directly in
naval bases like Brest and Toulon, and indirectly in the protection it gave
to the most rapidly expanding sector of the economy."  Plus ca change, plus
c'est la meme chose.

The new Controller General made no effort to restrain domestic or court
spending. The result was a peacetime spending spree and chronic budget
deficits.
Necker was neither a financial profligate nor an ultra royalist. He was
simply financing a war that the government deemed to be in the national
interest. During the conflict, he held down royal expenditures at home,
eliminated many sinecures, published a national budget in 1781, and
proposed the formation of a third provincial assembly. However, when his
request to join the royal council (as a Protestant, he was barred) was
rejected, he resigned. His immediate successor, Joly de Fleury, restored
many of the offices he had eliminated.

Upon the return of peace with the signing of the Treaty of Paris (1783),
the monarchy had another opportunity to institute economic, financial, and
political reforms, but it squandered it. Just as with the first Bush
administration after the Cold War, there would be no peace dividend. The
government was determined to exploit the vacuum created by British defeat
to restore French imperial power. Their global strategy was to maintain a
standing army of 150,000 men to defend the borders and preserve the balance
of power on the Continent while building up a transoceanic navy capable of
challenging the British in all the world's oceans. What is more, the new
Controller General, Calonne, made no effort to restrain domestic or court
spending. The result was a peacetime spending spree, chronic budget
deficits, and the addition of 700 million livres to the national debt. By
1788, debt service alone would absorb fifty percent of annual revenue. It
was guns and butter, French style. Today we are savoring it, Texas style.

In a few years, Calonne was faced with an imminent fiscal catastrophe. The
annual deficit in 1786 was projected to be 112 million livres, and the
American war loans would begin falling due the next year. Action was
imperative. Such was the power of liberal and federalist ideas in France
that Calonne summoned the Physiocrat Dupont de Nemours, a former Turgot
associate, to advise him. Meanwhile, with their blessing, the foreign
minister, Vergennes, signed a free trade agreement with Great Britain
(1786). With the help of Nemours, Calonne proposed the following measures
to open up the French economy: the deregulation of the domestic grain
trade, the dismantling of internal custom barriers, and commuting the
corvee into a public works tax. To raise a regular and equitable revenue,
he suggested a "territorial subvention," (i.e. a direct tax levied on all
landowners, without exception, to be assessed and levied by representative
provincial assemblies).

Calonne remembered the mistake Turgot had made ten years before. He had
relied exclusively on royal authority to enact his program and in so doing
had antagonized the nobility who did not like being presented with a fait
accompli. To avoid a similar fate, Calonne suggested the summoning of an
Assembly of Notables for early 1787 to consider, modify, and sanction the
reforms before they were sent to the Parlement of Paris for registration
(making them law). The king approved Calonne's whole program in December
1786. Here was the last chance for the monarchy to institute a program of
decentralist constitutional and liberal economic reform that would free the
economy, solve the fiscal crisis, transmute absolutism into
constitutionalism, and avert an impending political cataclysm.

Alas, as excellent and necessary as were Calonne's reforms, he was not the
right man to see them through. He was deeply unpopular for his lavish court
spending and for using his office to cultivate various corrupt stock
schemes. The nobility did not trust him, and the people despised him.
Recognizing he was a liability, the king dismissed him and appointed
Lomenie de Brienne in his stead. Brienne was a high noble, a Notable, and a
reformer. The Assembly was supportive of all the reforms, except the taxes.
Here they balked. Before they would give their sanction to new taxes, they
wanted the king to publish an annual budget and to agree to a permanent
commission of auditors.

Their concern was obvious. Why should they agree to changes that would
increase royal revenue if they had no way of monitoring royal expenses to
see if those funds were being prudently spent?  Now the king balked. He
thought the proposals an infringement on his prerogatives over the finances
and the budget. He vetoed them. It was a grievous error, but typical of the
vacillating mind of the king and the intellectual fetters of an absolutist
political tradition.   

The Parlement of Paris duly registered the decrees freeing the grain trade,
commuting the corvee, and setting up the provincial assemblies, but they
would not register the stamp duty or the land tax. They claimed that only
the Estates General, the medieval representative assembly of the three
estates of the kingdom (clergy, nobility, and commons) that had last met in
1614, could approve the taxes. The nobles were gambling that Louis would
never dare call for an assembly of the Estates. It was a clever stratagem
for defeating the tax proposals without incurring the popular odium for
doing so. The nobility and clergy would not give up their tax exemptions
nor grant the monarchy a potentially inexhaustible new source of revenue
without a share of political power. An unforeseen consequence was to create
a popular expectation for the reconvening of the Estates. This time the
nobility erred.

If the monarchy had not been so pressed for funds to stave off bankruptcy,
they could have declared the registered edicts a victory for reform and
waited for another day to deal with taxes. Not having that luxury, Brienne
and the king panicked. They decided to resort to the weapons of royal
absolutism to force through the tax reforms. They issued lits de justice
declaring the new taxes to be law by royal will. Second, they exiled the
recalcitrant Parlement to Troyes. The public outcry and institutional
resistance to these tyrannical measures was such that the monarchy had to
back down. The king recalled the Parlement and withdrew the lits de justice.

Brienne now requested that the Parlement register new royal loans to stave
off bankruptcy. It did so, but it again called for the re-convening of the
Estates General. It also attempted to establish its new position as a de
facto parliament. It declared that royal decrees were not law unless duly
registered by the parlements and denied the constitutionality of both lits
de justice and lettres de cachet (royal arrest warrants). The king and
Brienne believed that the future of royal absolutism was at stake, so they
responded with force. They surrounded the Parlement with troops. The king
stripped it of its powers of remonstrance and registry, and he invested
those powers in a new Plenary Court to be appointed by him.

The May coup turned both the nobility and the clergy against the Crown,
excited civil protest and unrest, and created a political crisis to match
the seriousness of the fiscal crisis. Once again, a foolish attempt to
preserve inviolate the senescent institutions of absolutism had failed.  By
August 1788, the monarchy was bankrupt and without credit. It could borrow
new funds neither in Paris nor Amsterdam. Brienne had no choice but to
resign. The king recalled Necker, who was the one man who had the
confidence of investors, was trusted by the nobility, and popular among the
masses. The king also summoned the Estates General to meet in May 1789.

The people would assemble by order in local assemblies and elect delegates.
The electorate would comprise over six million Frenchmen. Schama calls it
"the most numerous experiment in political representation attempted
anywhere in the world."  By tradition, the assemblies could draw up a list
of grievances and requests which their representatives would take with them
to Versailles. They would carry 25,000 of them. Students are taught that
the nobility and clergy were determined to preserve the old order, the
ancien regime, with most of their privileges intact, and admit only a
modicum of change, while the Third Estate demanded a transformed France in
which the watchwords would be liberty, progress, and modernity.

The truth is almost precisely the opposite. The majority of the nobility
envisioned a France that was rational, liberal, and constitutional. They
were willing to surrender their tax exemptions and seigniorial dues. They
called for the abolition of lettres de cachet and all forms of censorship;
they wanted an Anglo-Saxon style bill of rights with constitutional
protection for civil liberties. They recommended financial reforms: a
published national budget, the abolition of the sale of government offices,
and an end to tax farming. They also urged the abolition of the trade
guilds and the suppression of internal custom barriers.

While many of these recommendations are found in the cahiers of the Third
Estate, they are eclipsed by material concernsunderstandable complaints
about the high price of bread, the game laws, the gabelle (the salt tax),
and the depredations of the tax collectors. There are also numerous
criticisms of recent reforms, such as the free trade agreement with
England, the lifting of price controls on grain, agricultural enclosures,
and the granting of civil rights to Protestants.

In short, the voice of the Third Estate was largely one of reaction, and
while they wanted fewer taxes they wanted more government. According to
Schama, "much of the anger firing revolutionary violence arose from
hostility towards that modernization, rather than from impatience with the
speed of its progress." 

If only the French elites had reformed. There would have been no Terror, no
Napoleon, no centralizing, statist revolution.
The Third Estate had some liberal merchants and innovative industrialists,
but it had many more urban artisans and peasants. The latter believed they
were getting the shaft and that the nobility and clergy, as well as the
wealthy members of their own estate, were to blame. They wanted price
controls reimposed on grain, restrictions put on its exportation, the
prohibition of foreign manufactures, and the punishment of "speculators"
and "hoarders."  They found leaders among lawyer intellectuals of their own
estate, and some visionary members of the others, who spoke in a charged
language of grievance, polarity, and combat. Knowing little and caring less
about economic liberty or federal constitutionalism, they spoke of patriots
versus traitors, citizens versus aristocrats, virtue versus vice, the
nation assailed by its enemies. They offered the masses panaceas for their
plight, villains to blame, and promises that the possession of political
power would heave in the dikes of privilege and unleash the fountains of
wealth.

Schama correctly deduces that it was the politicization of the masses that
"turned a political crisis into a full-blooded revolution."  Once the vast
Third Estate was told that they were the nation and that a "true national
assembly would, by virtue of its higher moral qualityits common
patriotismprovide satisfaction, they were given a direct stake in sweeping
institutional change."  The abbe Sieyes' pamphlet What is the Third Estate?
appeared in January 1789 and would be to the French Revolution what Thomas
Paine's Common Sense (1776) had been to the American. By the time the
Estates General convened in May, the masses and leading intellectuals
regarded the continued existence of separate social orders with their own
institutional representation not only as an obstacle to reform, but as
unpatriotic, even treasonous. When the Estates General metastasized into
the National Assembly in June 1789, it was the onset of a radical
revolution. Liberty would not fare well on the guillotine.

Through 1788 and into 1789 the gods seemed to be conspiring to bring on a
popular revolution. A spring drought was followed by a devastating hail
storm in July. Crops were ruined. There followed one of the coldest winters
in French history. Grain prices skyrocketed. Even in the best of times, an
artisan or factor might spend 40 percent of his income on bread. By the end
of the year, 80 percent was not unusual. "It was the connection of anger
with hunger that made the Revolution possible," observed Schama. It was
also envy that drove the Revolution to its violent excesses and destructive
reform.

Take the Reveillon riots of April 1789. Reveillon was a successful Parisian
wall-paper manufacturer. He was not a noble but a self-made man who had
begun as an apprentice paper worker but now owned a factory that employed
400 well-paid operatives. He exported his finished products to England (no
mean feat). The key to his success was technical innovation, machinery, the
concentration of labor, and the integration of industrial processes, but
for all these the artisans of his district saw him as a threat to their
jobs. When he spoke out in favor of the deregulation of bread distribution
at an electoral meeting, an angry crowded marched on his factory, wrecked
it, and ransacked his home.

>From thenceforth, the Paris mob would be the power behind the Revolution.
Economic science would not fare well. According to Jean Baptiste Say, "The
moment there was any question in the National Assembly of commerce or
finances, violent invectives could be heard against the economists."  That
is what happens when political power is handed over to
pseudo-intellectuals, lawyers, and the mob.

The exponents of the rationalistic Enlightenment had stood for a
constitutional monarchy, a liberal economic and legal order, scientific
progress, and a competent administration. According to Schama, "They were
heirs to the reforming ethos of Louis XVI's reign, and authentic predictors
of the 'new notability' to emerge after the Revolution had run its course.
Their language was reasonable and their tempers cool. What they had in mind
was a nation vested, through its representatives, with the power to strip
away the obstructions to modernity. Such a state . . . would not wage war
on the France of the 1780s but consummate its promise."

If only the French elites could have agreed on a course of reform along
these lines, there would have been no Terror, no Napoleon, no centralizing,
statist revolution. And it was the pressing financial crisis, brought on by
deficit spending to fund a global empire that in the end frustrated the
kind of evolutionary political and economic liberalization that is the true
road of civilized progress.

__________________________

Historian Scott Trask is an adjunct scholar of the Mises Institute.
<mailto:hstrask at highstream.net>hstrask at highstream.net. See his 
<http://www.mises.org/articles.asp?mode=a&author=Trask>article
archive. Discuss this article on the <http://www.mises.org/blog>blog.

In response to many requests, it is now possible to set your credit-card
contribution to the Mises Institute to be recurring. You can easily set
this up on-line with a donation starting at $10 per month. See the
<https://www.mises.org/donate.asp>Membership Page. This is one way to
ensure that your support for the Mises Institute is ongoing.

<http://www.mises.org//fullstory.asp?printFriendly=Yes&control=1489>[Print
Friendly Page]

<http://www.mises.org/blog/>

<http://www.mises.org/elist.asp>Mises Email List Services

<https://www.mises.org/donate.asp>Join the Mises Institute
<http://www.mises.org/store>Mises.org Store

<http://www.mises.org/>Home | <http://www.mises.org/about.asp>About |
<http://www.mises.org/elist.asp>Email List |
<http://www.google.com/u/Mises>Search |
<http://www.mises.org/contact.asp>Contact Us |
<http://www.mises.org/journals.asp>Periodicals |
<http://www.mises.org/articles.asp>Articles |
<http://www.mises.org/fun.asp>Games & Fun
<http://www.mises.org/news.asp>News |
<http://www.mises.org/scholar.asp>Resources |
<http://www.mises.org/catalog.asp>Catalog |
<https://www.mises.org/donate.asp>Contributions |
<http://www.mises.org/calendar.asp>Freedom Calendar

You are subscribed as: rah at shipwright.com
Manage
<http://mises.biglist.com/list/article/?p=prefs&pre=l&e=1883638&pw=xujje2srnt>your
account. Unsubscribe
<http://mises.biglist.com/list/article/?p=unsub&pre=l&e=1883638&pw=xujje2srnt>here
or send email to <mailto:article-unsub-1883638 at mises.biglist.com>this
address.

--- end forwarded text


-- 
-----------------
R. A. Hettinga <mailto: rah at ibuc.com>
The Internet Bearer Underwriting Corporation <http://www.ibuc.com/>
44 Farquhar Street, Boston, MA 02131 USA
"... however it may deserve respect for its usefulness and antiquity,
[predicting the end of the world] has not been found agreeable to
experience." -- Edward Gibbon, 'Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire'





More information about the cypherpunks-legacy mailing list