People interested in economics may enjoy reading historian David Graeber's
David Graeber @davidgraeber Aug 2
David Graeber Retweeted Wladimir
wouldn't it be nice if this were true
Wladimir
@vvanwilgenburg
Turks believe there is US “secret” plan to deploy forces to Afrin to fulfill Kurds’ long-held dream reaching Sea
excellent book, Debt: The First 2000 Years. (Available free at https://archive.org/details/Debt-The_First_5000_Years)
Graeber argues that a) no actually-existing historical society used barter as a primary component of their economic system; and b) debt-money significantly predates both hard currency and markets.
Full text of the relevant chapter follows:
Chapter Two
THE MYTH OF BARTER
For every subtle and complicatedquestion, there is a perfectly simpleand straightforward answer, which iswrong.
— H.L. Mencken
WHAT IS THE DIFFERENCE between a mere obligation, a sense thatone ought to behave in a certain way, or even that one owes somethingto someone, and a debt, properly speaking? The answer is simple:money. The difference between a debt and an obligation is that a debtcan be precisely quantified. This requires money.
Not only is it money that makes debt possible: money and debt ap-pear on the scene at exactly the same time. Some of the very first writ-ten documents that have come down to us are Mesopotamian tabletsrecording credits and debits, rations issued by temples, money owedfor rent of temple lands, the value of each precisely specified in grainand silver. Some of the earliest works of moral philosophy, in turn, arereflections on what it means to imagine morality as debt — that is, interms of money.
A history of debt, then, is thus necessarily a history of money — andthe easiest way to understand the role that debt has played in humansociety is simply to follow the forms that money has taken, and theway money has been used, across the centuries — and the argumentsthat inevitably ensued about what all this means. Still, this is neces-sarily a very different history of money than we are used to. Wheneconomists speak of the origins of money, for example, debt is alwayssomething of an afterthought. First comes barter, then money; creditonly develops later. Even if one consults books on the history of moneyin, say, France, India, or China, what one generally gets is a historyof coinage, with barely any discussion of credit arrangements at all.For almost a century, anthropologists like me have been pointing out
22
DEBT
that there is something very wrong with this picture. The standardeconomic-history version has little to do with anything we observewhen we examine how economic life is actually conducted, in realcommunities and marketplaces, almost anywhere — where one is muchmore likely to discover everyone in debt to everyone else in a dozendifferent ways, and that most transactions take place without the useof currency.
Why the discrepancy?
Some of it is just the nature of the evidence: coins are preserved inthe archeological record; credit arrangements usually are not. Still, theproblem runs deeper. The existence of credit and debt has always beensomething of a scandal for economists, since it's almost impossible topretend that those lending and borrowing money are acting on purely"economic" motivations (for instance, that a loan to a stranger is thesame as a loan to one's cousin); it seems important, therefore, to beginthe story of money in an imaginary world from which credit and debthave been entirely erased. Before we can apply the tools of anthropol-ogy to reconstruct the real history of money, we need to understandwhat's wrong with the conventional account.
Economists generally speak of three functions of money: mediumof exchange, unit of account, and store of value. All economic text-books treat the first as primary. Here's a fairly typical extract fromEconomics, by Case, Fair, Gartner, and Heather (1996):
Money is vital to the working of a market economy. Imaginewhat life would be like without it. The alternative to a mon-etary economy is barter, people exchanging goods and servicesfor other goods and services directly instead of exchanging viathe medium of money.
How does a barter system work? Suppose you want crois-sants, eggs and orange juice for breakfast. Instead of going tothe grocer's and buying these things with money, you wouldhave to find someone who has these items and is willing totrade them. You would also have to have something the baker,the orange juice purveyor and the egg vendor want. Havingpencils to trade will do you no good if the baker and the or-ange juice and egg sellers do not want pencils.
A barter system requires a double coincidence of wants fortrade to take place. That is, to effect a trade, I need not onlyhave to find someone who has what I want, but that personmust also want what I have. Where the range of traded goodsis small, as it is in relatively unsophisticated economies, it is
THE MYTH OF BARTER
23
not difficult to find someone to trade with, and barter is oftenused. 1
This latter point is questionable, but it's phrased in so vague a way thatit would be hard to disprove.
In a complex society with many goods, barter exchanges in-volve an intolerable amount of effort. Imagine trying to findpeople who offer for sale all the things you buy in a typical tripto the grocer's, and who are willing to accept goods that youhave to offer in exchange for their goods.
Some agreed-upon medium of exchange (or means of pay-ment) neatly eliminates the double coincidence of wants prob-lem. 2
It's important to emphasize that this is not presented as somethingthat actually happened, but as a purely imaginary exercise. "To seethat society benefits from a medium of exchange" write Begg, Fischerand Dornbuch {Economics, 2005), "imagine a barter economy." "Imag-ine the difficulty you would have today," write Maunder, Myers, Wall,and Miller {Economics Explained, 1991), "if you had to exchange yourlabor directly for the fruits of someone else's labor." "Imagine," writeParkin and King {Economics, 1995), "you have roosters, but you wantroses." 3 One could multiply examples endlessly. Just about every eco-nomics textbook employed today sets out the problem the same way.Historically, they note, we know that there was a time when therewas no money. What must it have been like? Well, let us imagine aneconomy something like today's, except with no money. That wouldhave been decidedly inconvenient! Surely, people must have inventedmoney for the sake of efficiency.
The story of money for economists always begins with a fantasyworld of barter. The problem is where to locate this fantasy in timeand space: Are we talking about cave men, Pacific Islanders, the Ameri-can frontier? One textbook, by economists Joseph Stiglitz and JohnDriffill, takes us to what appears to be an imaginary New England orMidwestern town:
One can imagine an old-style farmer bartering with the black-smith, the tailor, the grocer, and the doctor in his small town.For simple barter to work, however, there must be a doublecoincidence of wants . . . Henry has potatoes and wants shoes,Joshua has an extra pair of shoes and wants potatoes. Bartering
24
DEBT
can make them both happier. But if Henry has firewood andJoshua does not need any of that, then bartering for Joshua'sshoes requires one or both of them to go searching for morepeople in the hope of making a multilateral exchange. Moneyprovides a way to make multilateral exchange much simpler.Henry sells his firewood to someone else for money and usesthe money to buy Joshua's shoes. 4
Again this is just a make-believe land much like the present, exceptwith money somehow plucked away. As a result it makes no sense:Who in their right mind would set up a grocery in such a place? Andhow would they get supplies? But let's leave that aside. There is asimple reason why everyone who writes an economics textbook feelsthey have to tell us the same story. For economists, it is in a very realsense the most important story ever told. It was by telling it, in thesignificant year of 1776, that Adam Smith, professor of moral philoso-phy at the University of Glasgow, effectively brought the discipline ofeconomics into being.
He did not make up the story entirely out of whole cloth. Alreadyin 330 bc, Aristotle was speculating along vaguely similar lines in histreatise on politics. At first, he suggested, families must have producedeverything they needed for themselves. Gradually, some would presum-ably have specialized, some growing corn, others making wine, swap-ping one for the other. 5 Money, Aristotle assumed, must have emergedfrom such a process. But, like the medieval schoolmen who occasion-ally repeated the story, Aristotle was never clear as to how. 6
In the years after Columbus, as Spanish and Portuguese adven-turers were scouring the world for new sources of gold and silver,these vague stories disappear. Certainly no one reported discovering aland of barter. Most sixteenth- and seventeenth-century travelers in theWest Indies or Africa assumed that all societies would necessarily havetheir own forms of money, since all societies had governments and allgovernments issued money. 7
Adam Smith, on the other hand, was determined to overturn theconventional wisdom of his day. Above all, he objected to the notionthat money was a creation of government. In this, Smith was the intel-lectual heir of the Liberal tradition of philosophers like John Locke,who had argued that government begins in the need to protect privateproperty and operated best when it tried to limit itself to that function.Smith expanded on the argument, insisting that property, money andmarkets not only existed before political institutions but were the veryfoundation of human society. It followed that insofar as government
THE MYTH OF BARTER
25
should play any role in monetary affairs, it should limit itself to guar-anteeing the soundness of the currency. It was only by making such anargument that he could insist that economics is itself a field of humaninquiry with its own principles and laws — that is, as distinct from, sayethics or politics.
Smith's argument is worth laying out in detail because it is, as Isay, the great founding myth of the discipline of economics.
What, he begins, is the basis of economic life, properly speaking?It is "a certain propensity in human nature . . . the propensity to truck,barter, and exchange one thing for another." Animals don't do this."Nobody," Smith observes, "ever saw a dog make a fair and deliberateexchange of one bone for another with another dog." 8 But humans, ifleft to their own devices, will inevitably begin swapping and comparingthings. This is just what humans do. Even logic and conversation arereally just forms of trading, and as in all things, humans will alwaystry to seek their own best advantage, to seek the greatest profit theycan from the exchange. 9
It is this drive to exchange, in turn, which creates that division oflabor responsible for all human achievement and civilization. Here thescene shifts to another one of those economists' faraway fantasylands —it seems to be an amalgam of North American Indians and CentralAsian pastoral nomads: 10
In a tribe of hunters or shepherds a particular person makesbows and arrows, for example, with more readiness and dex-terity than any other. He frequently exchanges them for cattleor for venison with his companions; and he finds at last thathe can in this manner get more cattle and venison, than if hehimself went to the field to catch them. From a regard to hisown interest, therefore, the making of bows and arrows growsto be his chief business, and he becomes a sort of armourer.Another excels in making the frames and covers of their littlehuts or moveable houses. He is accustomed to be of use in thisway to his neighbours, who reward him in the same mannerwith cattle and with venison, till at last he finds it his interestto dedicate himself entirely to this employment, and to becomea sort of house-carpenter. In the same manner a third becomesa smith or a brazier; a fourth a tanner or dresser of hides orskins, the principal- part of the clothing of savages . . .
It's only once we have expert arrow-makers, wigwam-makers, andso on that people start realizing there's a problem. Notice how, as in
26
DEBT
so many examples, we have a tendency to slip from imaginary savagesto small-town shopkeepers.
' But when the division of labor first began to take place, thispower of exchanging must frequently have been very muchclogged and embarrassed in its operations. One man, we shallsuppose, has more of a certain commodity than he himself hasoccasion for, while another has less. The former consequentlywould be glad to dispose of, and the latter to purchase, a partof this superfluity. But if this latter should chance to have noth-ing that the former stands in need of, no exchange can be madebetween them. The butcher has more meat in his shop thanhe himself can consume, and the brewer and the baker wouldeach of them be willing to purchase a part of it. But they havenothing to offer in exchange . . .
In order to avoid the inconveniency of such situations, everyprudent man in every period of society, after the first establish-ment of the division of labor, must naturally have endeavoredto manage his affairs in such a manner, as to have at all timesby him, besides the peculiar produce of his own industry, acertain quantity of some one commodity or other, such as heimagined that few people would be likely to refuse in exchangefor the produce of their industry."
So everyone will inevitably start stockpiling something they figurethat everyone else is likely to want. This has a paradoxical effect,because at a certain point, rather than making that commodity lessvaluable (since everyone already has some) it becomes more valuable(because it becomes, effectively, currency):
Salt is said to be the common instrument of commerce andexchanges in Abyssinia; a species of shells in some parts ofthe coast of India; dried cod at Newfoundland; tobacco inVirginia; sugar in some of our West India colonies; hides ordressed leather in some other countries; and there is at this daya village in Scotland where it is not uncommon, I am told, fora workman to carry nails instead of money to the baker's shopor the ale-house.' 2
THE MYTH OF BARTER
27
Eventually, of course, at least for long-distance trade, it all boilsdown to precious metals, since these are ideally suited to serve as cur-rency, being durable, portable, and able to be endlessly subdivided intoidentical portions.
Different metals have been made use of by different nationsfor this purpose. Iron was the common instrument of com-merce among the ancient Spartans; copper among the ancientRomans; and gold and silver among all rich and commercialnations.
Those metals seem originally to have been made use of for thispurpose in rude bars, without any stamp or coinage . . .
The use of metals in this rude state was attended with two veryconsiderable inconveniencies; first with the trouble of weigh-ing; and, secondly, with that of assaying them. In the preciousmetals, where a small difference in the quantity makes a greatdifference in the value, even the business of weighing, withproper exactness, requires at least very accurate weights andscales. The weighing of gold in particular is an operation ofsome nicety . . . 13
It's easy to see where this is going. Using irregular metal ingots iseasier than barter, but wouldn't standardizing the units — say, stamp-ing pieces of metal with uniform designations guaranteeing weight andfineness, in different denominations — make things easier still? Clearly itwould, and so was coinage born. True, issuing coinage meant govern-ments had to get involved, since they generally ran the mints; but in thestandard version of the story, governments have only this one limitedrole — to guarantee the money supply — and tend to do it badly, sincethroughout history, unscrupulous kings have often cheated by debasingthe coinage and causing inflation and other sorts of political havoc inwhat was originally a matter of simple economic common sense.
Tellingly, this story played a crucial role not only in founding thediscipline of economics, but in the very idea that there was somethingcalled "the economy," which operated by its own rules, separate frommoral or political life, that economists could take as their field of study.
28
DEBT
"The economy" is where we indulge in our natural propensity to truckand barter. We are still trucking and bartering. We always will be.Money is simply the most efficient means.
Economists like Karl Menger and Stanley Jevons later improvedon the details of the story, most of all by adding various mathemati-cal equations to demonstrate that a random assortment of people withrandom desires could, in theory, produce not only a single commodityto use as money but a uniform price system. In the process, they alsosubstituted all sorts of impressive technical vocabulary (i.e., "inconve-niences" became "transaction costs"). The crucial thing, though, is thatby now, this story has become simple common sense for most people.We teach it to children in schoolbooks and museums. Everybody knowsit. "Once upon a time, there was barter. It was difficult. So people in-vented money. Then came the development of banking and credit." Itall forms a perfectly simple, straightforward progression, a process ofincreasing sophistication and abstraction that has carried humanity,logically and inexorably, from the Stone Age exchange of mastodontusks to stock markets, hedge funds, and securitized derivatives.' 4
It really has become ubiquitous. Wherever we find money, we alsofind the story. At one point, in the town of Arivonimamo, in Madagas-car, I had the privilege of interviewing a Kalanoro, a tiny ghostly crea-ture that a local spirit medium claimed to keep hidden away in a chestin his home. The spirit belonged to the brother of a notorious localloan shark, a horrible woman named Nordine, and to be honest I wasa bit reluctant to have anything to do with the family, but some of myfriends insisted — since after all, this was a creature from ancient times.The creature spoke from behind a screen in an eerie, otherworldly qua-ver. But all it was really interested in talking about was money. Finally,slightly exasperated by the whole charade, I asked, "So, what did youuse for money back in ancient times, when you were still alive?"
The mysterious voice immediately replied, "No. We didn't usemoney. In ancient times we used to barter commodities directly, onefor the other ..."
The story, then, is everywhere. It is the founding myth of our system ofeconomic relations. It is so deeply established in common sense, evenin places like Madagascar, that most people on earth couldn't imagineany other way that money possibly could have come about.
The problem is there's no evidence that it ever happened, and anenormous amount of evidence suggesting that it did not.
THE MYTH OF BARTER
29
For centuries now, explorers have been trying to find this fabledland of barter — none with success. Adam Smith set his story in aborigi-nal North America (others preferred Africa or the Pacific). In Smith'stime, at least it could be said that reliable information on Native Amer-ican economic systems was unavailable in Scottish libraries. But bymid-century, Lewis Henry Morgan's descriptions of the Six Nationsof the Iroquois, among others, were widely published — and they madeclear that the main economic institution among the Iroquois nationswere longhouses where most goods were stockpiled and then allocatedby women's councils, and no one ever traded arrowheads for slabs ofmeat. Economists simply ignored this information. 15 Stanley Jevons,for example, who in 1871 wrote what has come to be considered theclassic book on the origins of money, took his examples straight fromSmith, with Indians swapping venison for elk and beaver hides, andmade no use of actual descriptions of Indian life that made it clear thatSmith had simply made this up. Around that same time, missionaries,adventurers, and colonial administrators were fanning out across theworld, many bringing copies of Smith's book with them, expecting tofind the land of barter. None ever did. They discovered an almost end-less variety of economic systems. But to this day, no one has been ableto locate a part of the world where the ordinary mode of economictransaction between neighbors takes the form of "I'll give you twentychickens for that cow."
The definitive anthropological work on barter, by Caroline Hum-phrey, of Cambridge, could not be more definitive in its conclusions:"No example of a barter economy, pure and simple, has ever beendescribed, let alone the emergence from it of money; all available eth-nography suggests that there never has been such a thing." 1 *
Now, all this hardly means that barter does not exist — or eventhat it's never practiced by the sort of people that Smith would refer toas "savages." It just means that it's almost never employed, as Smithimagined, between fellow villagers. Ordinarily, it takes place betweenstrangers, even enemies. Let us begin with the Nambikwara of Brazil.They would seem to fit all the criteria: they are a simple society with-out much in the way of division of labor, organized into small bandsthat traditionally numbered at best a hundred people each. Occasion-ally if one band spots the cooking fires of another in their vicinity, theywill send emissaries to negotiate a meeting for purposes of trade. If theoffer is accepted, they will first hide their women and children in theforest, then invite the men of other band to visit camp. Each band hasa chief; once everyone has been assembled, each chief gives a formalspeech praising the other party and belittling his own; everyone puts
30
DEBT
aside their weapons to sing and dance together — though the dance isone that mimics military confrontation. Then, individuals from eachside approach each other to trade:
If an individual wants an object he extols it by saying how fineit is. If a man values an object and wants much in exchange forit, instead of saying that it is very valuable he says that it is nogood, thus showing his desire to keep it. "This axe is no good,it is very old, it is very dull," he will say, referring to his axewhich the other wants.
This argument is carried on in an angry tone of voice un-til a settlement is reached. When agreement has been reachedeach snatches the object out of the other's hand. If a man hasbartered a necklace, instead of taking it off and handing itover, the other person must take it off with a show of force.Disputes, often leading to fights, occur when one party is alittle premature and snatches the object before the other hasfinished arguing. 17
The whole business concludes with a great feast at which the wom-en reappear, but this too can lead to problems, since amidst the musicand good cheer, there is ample opportunity for seductions. 18 This some-times led to jealous quarrels. Occasionally, people would get killed.
Barter, then, for all the festive elements, was carried out be-tween people who might otherwise be enemies and hovered about aninch away from outright warfare — and, if the ethnographer is to bebelieved — if one side later decided they had been taken advantage of, itcould very easily lead to actual wars.
To shift our spotlight halfway around the world to Western Arn-hem Land in Australia, where the Gunwinggu people are famous forentertaining neighbors in rituals of ceremonial barter called the dza-malag. Here the threat of actual violence seems much more distant.Partly, this is because things are made easier by the existence of a moi-ety system that embraces the whole region: no one is allowed to marry,or even have sex with, people of their own moiety, no matter wherethey come from, but anyone from the other is technically a potentialmatch. Therefore, for a man, even in distant communities, half thewomen are strictly forbidden, half of them fair game. The region is alsounited by local specialization: each people has its own trade product tobe bartered with the others.
What follows is from a description of a dzamalag held in the 1940s,as observed by an anthropologist named Ronald Berndt.
THE MYTH OF BARTER
31
Once again, it begins as strangers, after some initial negotiations,are invited into the hosts' main camp. The visitors in this particularexample were famous for their "much-prized serrated spears" — theirhosts had access to good European cloth. The trading begins whenthe visiting party, which consisted of both men and women, entersthe camp's dancing ground of "ring place," and three of them beganto entertain their hosts with music. Two men start singing, a third ac-companies them on the didjeridu. Before long, women from the hosts'side come and attack the musicians:
Men and women rise and begin to dance. The dzamalag openswhen two Gunwinggu women of the opposite moiety to thesinging men "give dzamalag" to the latter. They present eachman with a piece of cloth, and hit or touch him, pulling himdown on the ground, calling him a dzamalag husband, andjoking with him in an erotic vein. Then another woman of theopposite moiety to the pipe player gives him cloth, hits andjokes with him.
This sets in motion the dzamalag exchange. Men from thevisiting group sit quietly while women of the opposite moietycome over and give them cloth, hit them, and invite them tocopulate; they take any liberty they choose with the men, amidamusement and applause, while the singing and dancing con-tinue. Women try to undo the men's loin coverings or touchtheir penises, and to drag them from the "ring place" for co-itus. The men go with their dzamalag partners, with a show ofreluctance, to copulate in the bushes away from the fires whichlight up the dancers. They may give the women tobacco orbeads. When the women return, they give part of this tobaccoto their own husbands, who have encouraged them to go dza-malag. The husbands, in turn, use the tobacco to pay their ownfemale dzamalag partners . .
New singers and musicians appear, are again assaulted and draggedoff to the bushes; men encourage their wives "not to be shy," so as tomaintain the Gunwinggu reputation for hospitality; eventually thosemen also take the initiative with the visitors' wives, offering cloth, hit-ting them, and leading them off into the bushes. Beads and tobaccocirculate. Finally, once participants have all paired off at least once,and the guests are satisfied with the cloth they have acquired, thewomen stop dancing and stand in two rows and the visitors line up torepay them.
32
DEBT
Then visiting men of one moiety dance towards the womenof the opposite moiety, in order to "give them dzamalag."They hold shovel-nosed spears poised, pretending to spear thewomen, but instead hit them with the flat of the blade. "Wewill not spear you, for we have already speared you with ourpenises." They present the spears to the women. Then visitingmen of the other moiety go through the same actions with thewomen of their opposite moiety, giving them spears with ser-rated points. This terminates the ceremony, which is followedby a large distribution of food. 20
This is a particularly dramatic case, but dramatic cases are reveal-ing. What the Gunwinggu hosts appear to have been able to do here,owing to the relatively amicable relations between neighboring peoplesin Western Arnhem Land, is to take all the elements in Nambikwarabarter (the music and dancing, the potential hostility, the sexual in-trigue), and turn it all into a kind of festive game — one not, perhaps,without its dangers, but (as the ethnographer emphasizes) consideredenormous fun by everyone concerned.
What all such cases of trade through barter have in common is thatthey are meetings with strangers who will, likely as not, never meetagain, and with whom one certainly will not enter into any ongoing re-lations. This is why a direct one-on-one exchange is appropriate: eachside makes their trade and walks away. It's all made possible by layingdown an initial mantle of sociability, in the form of shared pleasures,music and dance — the usual base of conviviality on which trade mustalways be built. Then comes the actual trading, where both sides makea great display of the latent hostility that necessarily exists in any ex-change of material goods between strangers — where neither party hasno particular reason not to take advantage of the other — by playfulmock aggression, though in the Nambikwara case, where the mantleof sociability is extremely thin, mock aggression is in constant dangerof slipping over into the real thing. The Gunwinggu, with their morerelaxed attitude toward sexuality, have quite ingeniously managed tomake the shared pleasures and aggression into exactly the same thing.
Recall here the language of the economics textbooks: "Imagine asociety without money." "Imagine a barter economy." One thing theseexamples make abundantly clear is just how limited the imaginativepowers of most economists turn out to be. 21
Why? The simplest answer would be: for there to even be a disci-pline called "economics," a discipline that concerns itself first and fore-most with how individuals seek the most advantageous arrangement
THE MYTH OF BARTER
33
for the exchange of shoes for potatoes, or cloth for spears, it mustassume that the exchange of such goods need have nothing to do withwar, passion, adventure, mystery, sex, or death. Economics assumes adivision between different spheres of human behavior that, among peo-ple like the Gunwinngu and the Nambikwara, simply does not exist.These divisions in turn are made possible by very specific institutionalarrangements: the existence of lawyers, prisons, and police, to ensurethat even people who don't like each other very much, who have nointerest in developing any kind of ongoing relationship, but are simplyinterested in getting their hands on as much of the others' possessionsas possible, will nonetheless refrain from the most obvious expedient(theft). This in turn allows us to assume that life is neatly divided be-tween the marketplace, where we do our shopping, and the "sphereof consumption," where we concern ourselves with music, feasts, andseduction. In other words, the vision of the world that forms the basisof the economics textbooks, which Adam Smith played so large a partin promulgating, has by now become so much a part of our commonsense that we find it hard to imagine any other possible arrangement.
From these examples, it begins to be clear why there are no societ-ies based on barter. Such a society could only be one in which every-body was an inch away from everybody else's throat; but nonethelesshovering there, poised to strike but never actually striking, forever.True, barter does sometimes occur between people who do not consid-er each other strangers, but they're usually people who might as well bestrangers — that is, who feel no sense of mutual responsibility or trust,or the desire to develop ongoing relations. The Pukhtun of NorthernPakistan, for instance, are famous for their open-handed hospitality.Barter is what you do with those to whom you are not bound by tiesof hospitality (or kinship, or much of anything else):
A favorite mode of exchange among men is barter, or adal-badal (give and take). Men are always on the alert for thepossibility of bartering one of their possessions for somethingbetter. Often the exchange is like for like: a radio for a radio,sunglasses for sunglasses, a watch for a watch. However, un-like objects can also be exchanged, such as, in one instance, abicycle for two donkeys. Adal-badal is always practiced withnon-relatives and affords men a great deal of pleasure as theyattempt to get the advantage over their exchange partner. Agood exchange, in which a man feels he has gotten the betterof the deal, is cause for bragging and pride. If the exchange isbad, the recipient tries to renege on the deal or, failing that, to
34
DEBT
palm off the faulty object on someone unsuspecting. The bestpartner in adal-badal is someone who is distant spatially andwill therefore have little opportunity to complain. 22
Neither are such unscrupulous motives limited to Central Asia.They seem inherent to the very nature of barter — which would explainthe fact that in the century or two before Smith's time, the Englishwords "truck and barter," like their equivalents in French, Spanish,German, Dutch, and Portuguese, literally meant "to trick, bamboozle,or rip off." 23 Swapping one thing directly for another while trying toget the best deal one can out of the transaction is, ordinarily, howone deals with people one doesn't care about and doesn't expect tosee again. What reason is there not to try to take advantage of sucha person? If, on the other hand, one cares enough about someone — aneighbor, a friend — to wish to deal with her fairly and honestly, onewill inevitably also care about her enough to take her individual needs,desires, and situation into account. Even if you do swap one thing foranother, you are likely to frame the matter as a gift.
To illustrate what I mean by this, let's return to the economics text-books and the problem of the "double coincidence of wants." Whenwe left Henry, he needed a pair of shoes, but all he had lying aroundwere some potatoes. Joshua had an extra pair of shoes, but he didn'treally need potatoes. Since money has not yet been invented, they havea problem. What are they to do?
The first thing that should be clear by now is that we'd really haveto know a bit more about Joshua and Henry. Who are they? Are theyrelated? If so, how? They appear to live in a small community. Any twopeople who have been living their lives in the same small communitywill have some sort of complicated history with each other. Are theyfriends, rivals, allies, lovers, enemies, or several of these things at once?
The authors of the original example seem to assume two neighborsof roughly equal status, not closely related, but on friendly terms — thatis, as close to neutral equality as one can get. Even so, this doesn't saymuch. For example, if Henry was living in a Seneca longhouse, andneeded shoes, Joshua would not even enter into it; he'd simply men-tion it to his wife, who'd bring up the matter with the other matrons,fetch materials from the longhouse's collective storehouse, and sew himsome. Alternately, to find a scenario fit for an imaginary economics
THE MYTH OF BARTER
35
textbook, we might place Joshua and Henry together in a small, inti-mate community like a Nambikwara or Gunwinggu band.
SCENARIO 1
Henry walks up to Joshua and says "Nice shoes!"
Joshua says, "Oh, they're not much, but since you seem to likethem, by all means take them."
Henry takes the shoes.
Henry's potatoes are not at issue since both parties are perfectlywell aware that if Joshua were ever short of potatoes, Henry wouldgive him some.
And that's about it. Of course it's not clear, in this case, how longHenry will actually get to keep the shoes. It probably depends on hownice they are. If they were just ordinary shoes, this might be the end ofthe matter. If they are in any way unique or beautiful, they might endup being passed around. There's a famous story that John and LornaMarshall, who carried out a study of Kalahari Bushmen in the '60s,once gave a knife to one of their favorite informants. They left andcame back a year later, only to discover that pretty much everyone inthe band had been in possession of the knife at some point in between.On the other hand, several Arab friends confirm to me that in lessstrictly egalitarian contexts, there is an expedient. If a friend praises abracelet or bag, you are normally expected to immediately say "takeit" — but if you are really determined to hold on to it, you can alwayssay, "yes, isn't it beautiful? It was a gift."
But clearly, the authors of the textbook have a slightly more im-personal transaction in mind. The authors seem to imagine the twomen as the heads of patriarchal households, on good terms with eachother, but who keep their own supplies. Perhaps they live in one ofthose Scottish villages with the butcher and the baker in Adam Smith'sexamples, or a colonial settlement in New England. Except for somereason they've never heard of money. It's a peculiar fantasy, but let'ssee what we can do:
SCENARIO 2
Henry walks up to Joshua and says, "Nice shoes!"
Or, perhaps — let's make this a bit more realistic — Henry's wifeis chatting with Joshua's and strategically lets slip that the state ofHenry's shoes is getting so bad he's complaining about corns.
36
DEBT
The message is conveyed, and Joshua comes by the next day tooffer his extra pair to Henry as a present, insisting that this is justa neighborly gesture. He would certainly never want anything inreturn.
It doesn't matter whether Joshua is sincere in saying this. By do-ing so, Joshua thereby registers a credit. Henry owes him one.
How might Henry pay Joshua back? There are endless possi-bilities. Perhaps Joshua really does want potatoes. Henry waits adiscrete interval and drops them off, insisting that this too is just agift. Or Joshua doesn't need potatoes now but Henry waits until hedoes. Or maybe a year later, Joshua is planning a banquet, so hecomes strolling by Henry's barnyard and says "Nice pig . . ."
In any of these scenarios, the problem of "double coincidence ofwants," so endlessly invoked in the economics textbooks, simply disap-pears. Henry might not have something Joshua wants right now. Butif the two are neighbors, it's obviously only a matter of time beforehe will. 24
This in turn means that the need to stockpile commonly acceptableitems in the way that Smith suggested disappears as well. With it goesthe need to develop currency. As with so many actual small communi-ties, everyone simply keeps track of who owes what to whom.
There is just one major conceptual problem here — one the atten-tive reader might have noticed. Henry "owes Joshua one." One what?How do you quantify a favor? On what basis do you say that thismany potatoes, or this big a pig, seems more or less equivalent to apair of shoes? Because even if these things remain rough-and-ready ap-proximations, there must be some way to establish that X is roughlyequivalent to Y, or slightly worse or slightly better. Doesn't this implythat something like money, at least in the sense of a unit of accountsby which one can compare the value of different objects, already hasto exist?
In most gift economies, there actually is a rough-and-ready wayto solve the problem. One establishes a series of ranked categories oftypes of thing. Pigs and shoes may be considered objects of roughlyequivalent status, one can give one in return for the other; coral neck-laces are quite another matter, one would have to give back anothernecklace, or at least another piece of jewelry — anthropologists are usedto referring to these as creating different "spheres of exchange." 25 Thisdoes simplify things somewhat. When cross-cultural barter becomes aregular and unexceptional thing, it tends to operate according to simi-lar principles: there are only certain things traded for certain others
THE MYTH OF BARTER
37
(cloth for spears, for example), which makes it easy to work out tra-ditional equivalences. However, this doesn't help us at all with theproblem of the origin of money. Actually, it makes it infinitely worse.Why stockpile salt or gold or fish if they can only be exchanged forsome things and not others?
In fact, there is good reason to believe that barter is not a par-ticularly ancient phenomenon at all, but has only really become wide-spread in modern times. Certainly in most of the cases we know about,it takes place between people who are familiar with the use of money,but for one reason or another, don't have a lot of it around. Elaboratebarter systems often crop up in the wake of the collapse of nationaleconomies: most recently in Russia in the '90s, and in Argentina around2002, when rubles in the first case, and dollars in the second, effectivelydisappeared. 26 Occasionally one can even find some kind of currencybeginning to develop: for instance, in POW camps and many prisons,inmates have indeed been known to use cigarettes as a kind of cur-rency, much to the delight and excitement of professional economists. 27But here too we are talking about people who grew up using moneyand now have to make do without it — exactly the situation "imagined"by the economics textbooks with which I began.
The more frequent solution is to adopt some sort of credit system.When much of Europe "reverted to barter" after the collapse of theRoman Empire, and then again after the Carolingian Empire likewisefell apart, this seems to be what happened. People continued keepingaccounts in the old imperial currency, even if they were no longer us-ing coins. 28 Similarly, the Pukhtun men who like to swap bicycles fordonkeys are hardly unfamiliar with the use of money. Money has ex-isted in that part of the world for thousands of years. They just preferdirect exchange between equals — in this case, because they consider itmore manly. 29
The most remarkable thing is that even in Adam Smith's examplesof fish and nails and tobacco being used as money, the same sort ofthing was happening. In the years following the appearance of TheWealth of Nations, scholars checked into most of those examples anddiscovered that in just about every case, the people involved were quitefamiliar with the use of money, and in fact, were using money — as aunit of account. 30 Take the example of dried cod, supposedly used asmoney in Newfoundland. As the British diplomat A. Mitchell-Innespointed out almost a century ago, what Smith describes was really anillusion, created by a simple credit arrangement:
38
DEBT
In the early days of the Newfoundland fishing industry, therewas no permanent European population; the fishers went therefor the fishing season only, and those who were not fisherswere traders who bought the dried fish and sold to the fisherstheir daily supplies. The latter sold their catch to the traders atthe market price in pounds, shillings and pence, and obtainedin return a credit on their books, with which they paid for theirsupplies. Balances due by the traders were paid for by drafts onEngland or France. 31
It was quite the same in the Scottish village. It's not as if anyoneactually walked into the local pub, plunked down a roofing nail, andasked for a pint of beer. Employers in Smith's day often lacked cointo pay their workers; wages could be delayed by a year or more; inthe meantime, it was considered acceptable for employees to carry offeither some of their own products or leftover work materials, lumber,fabric, cord, and so on. The nails were de facto interest on what theiremployers owed them. So they went to the pub, ran up a tab, and whenoccasion permitted, brought in a bag of nails to charge off against thedebt. The law making tobacco legal tender in Virginia seems to havebeen an attempt by planters to oblige local merchants to accept theirproducts as a credit around harvest time. In effect, the law forced allmerchants in Virginia to become middlemen in the tobacco business,whether they liked it or not; just as all West Indian merchants wereobliged to become sugar dealers, since that's what all their wealthiercustomers brought in to write off against their debt.
The primary examples, then, were ones in which people wereimprovising credit systems, because actual money — gold and silvercoinage — was in short supply. But the most shocking blow to the con-ventional version of economic history came with the translation, first ofEgyptian hieroglyphics, and then of Mesopotamian cuneiform, whichpushed back scholars' knowledge of written history almost three mil-lennia, from the time of Homer (circa 800 bc), where it had hovered inSmith's time, to roughly 3500 bc. What these texts revealed was thatcredit systems of exactly this sort actually preceded the invention ofcoinage by thousands of years.
The Mesopotamian system is the best-documented, more so thanthat of Pharaonic Egypt (which appears similar), Shang China (aboutwhich we know little), or the Indus Valley civilization (about whichwe know nothing at all). As it happens, we know a great deal aboutMesopotamia, since the vast majority of cuneiform documents werefinancial in nature.
THE MYTH OF BARTER
39
The Sumerian economy was dominated by vast temple and palacecomplexes. These were often staffed by thousands: priests and officials,craftspeople who worked in their industrial workshops, farmers andshepherds who worked their considerable estates. Even though ancientSumer was usually divided into a large number of independent city-states, by the time the curtain goes up on Mesopotamian civilizationaround 3500, temple administrators already appear to have developeda single, uniform system of accountancy — one that is in some waysstill with us, actually, because it's to the Sumerians that we owe suchthings as the dozen or the 24-hour day. 32 The basic monetary unit wasthe silver shekel. One shekel's weight in silver was established as theequivalent of one gur, or bushel of barley. A shekel was subdividedinto 60 minas, corresponding to one portion of barley — on the prin-ciple that there were 30 days in a month, and Temple workers receivedtwo rations of barley every day. It's easy to see that "money" in thissense is in no way the product of commercial transactions. It was ac-tually created by bureaucrats in order to keep track of resources andmove things back and forth between departments.
Temple bureaucrats used the system to calculate debts (rents, fees,loans . . .) in silver. Silver was, effectively, money. And it did indeedcirculate in the form of unworked chunks, "rude bars" as Smith hadput it. 33 In this he was right. But it was almost the only part of his ac-count that was right. One reason was that silver did not circulate verymuch. Most of it just sat around in Temple and Palace treasuries, someof which remained, carefully guarded, in the same place for literallythousands of years. It would have been easy enough to standardize theingots, stamp them, create some authoritative system to guarantee theirpurity. The technology existed. Yet no one saw any particular need todo so. One reason was that while debts were calculated in silver, theydid not have to be paid in silver — in fact, they could be paid in moreor less anything one had around. Peasants who owed money to theTemple or Palace, or to some Temple or Palace official, seem to havesettled their debts mostly in barley, which is why fixing the ratio of sil-ver to barley was so important. But it was perfectly acceptable to showup with goats, or furniture, or lapis lazuli. Temples and Palaces werehuge industrial operations — they could find a use for almost anything. 34
In the marketplaces that cropped up in Mesopotamian cities, pric-es were also calculated in silver, and the prices of commodities thatweren't entirely controlled by the Temples and Palaces would tend tofluctuate according to supply and demand. But even here, such evidenceas we have suggests that most transactions were based on credit. Mer-chants (who sometimes worked for the Temples, sometimes operated
40
DEBT
independently) were among the few people who did, often, actually usesilver in transactions; but even they mostly did much of their dealingson credit, and ordinary people buying beer from "ale women," or lo-cal innkeepers, once again, did so by running up a tab, to be settled atharvest time in barley or anything they might have had at hand. 35
At this point, just about every aspect of the conventional story ofthe origins of money lay in rubble. Rarely has an historical theory beenso absolutely and systematically refuted. By the early decades of thetwentieth century, all the pieces were in place to completely rewritethe history of money. The groundwork was laid by Mitchell-Innes —the same one I've already cited on the matter of the cod — in two essaysthat appeared in New York's Banking Law Journal in 1913 and 1914.In these, Mitchell-Innes matter-of-factly laid out the false assumptionson which existing economic history was based and suggested that whatwas really needed was a history of debt:
One of the popular fallacies in connection with commerce isthat in modern days a money-saving device has been intro-duced called credit and that, before this device was known,all, purchases were paid for in cash, in other words in coins. Acareful investigation shows that the precise reverse is true. Inolden days coins played a far smaller part in commerce thanthey do to-day. Indeed so small was the quantity of coins, thatthey did not even suffice for the needs of the [Medieval Eng-lish] Royal household and estates which regularly used tokensof various kinds for the purpose of making small payments. Sounimportant indeed was the coinage that sometimes Kings didnot hesitate to call it all in for re-minting and re-issue and stillcommerce went on just the same. 36
In fact, our standard account of monetary history is preciselybackwards. We did not begin with barter, discover money, and theneventually develop credit systems. It happened precisely the other wayaround. What we now call virtual money came first. Coins came muchlater, and their use spread only unevenly, never completely replacingcredit systems. Barter, in turn, appears to be largely a kind of acciden-tal byproduct of the use of coinage or paper money: historically, it hasmainly been what people who are used to cash transactions do whenfor one reason or another they have no access to currency.
The curious thing is that it never happened. This new history wasnever written. It's not that any economist has ever refuted Mitchell-Innes.They just ignored him. Textbooks did not change their story — even if
THE MYTH OF BARTER
41
all the evidence made clear that the story was simply wrong. Peoplestill write histories of money that are actually histories of coinage, onthe assumption that in the past, these were necessarily the same thing;periods when coinage largely vanished are still described as times whenthe economy "reverted to barter," as if the meaning of this phrase isself-evident, even though no one actually knows what it means. As aresult we have next-to-no idea how, say, the inhabitant of a Dutchtown in 950 ad actually went about acquiring cheese or spoons or hir-ing musicians to play at his daughter's wedding — let alone how any ofthis was likely to be arranged in Pemba or Samarkand.'
On Sat, Aug 5, 2017 at 10:53 PM, Razer <g2s@riseup.net> wrote:
Hackermoon...
13.7 billion years ago, the Big Bang brought the universe into existence. 3.8 billion years ago, life first appeared on our planet. 1.9 million years ago, Earth witnessed a hominid species, Home erectus, walking upright for the first time.
And, 7,000 years ago, money was invented.But first, people bartered.
Not everyone had everything. We always had something in surplus, and we always needed something that the other person had. As the common sense would have said, we started exchanging our surplus assets for what we needed.
Imagine I had extra apples and you had extra oranges, we could simply exchange fruits with one another.
What if I had a surplus of apples, and didn’t want your oranges, but I’d love to have some strawberries.
You would go and find someone who can give you strawberries in exchange for your oranges. Luckily you find your friend, Joe, to barter with you.
Then, you’d bring me those strawberries, and I’d give you some apples.Joe, you and I are all happy.
(Did I mention the lovely illustrations?)
But what if Joe had a surplus of bananas, but he didn’t want your oranges either? That would be a problem.
The smart among us started asking a profound question, “Can there be something that everyone wants?”
Then, there was commodity money.
There were a few things that almost everyone used, like salt, seeds, sheep, and cows. They became the commodity money. If we had any of these, we could use them to get whatever we wanted....
In full at hACKERMOON: https://hackernoon.com/wtf-is-
money-2a5d78072128